Notes
-
[1]
Monia Ghazali, Lecturer, laboratoire LEDA, Université Paris Dauphine (moniaghazali@ yahoo. fr).
-
[2]
Studies refer to the role of FDI, outsourcing, skill-biased technological change, the increase of the returns to education, the extension of the informal sector due to trade reforms…
-
[3]
We should note that Tunisia as other North African countries observes a paradox related to the high level of college graduates unemployment. The neoclassical trade theory does not involve such hypothesis. Furthermore, the majority of developing countries did not experience a uniform trade protection pattern across sectors, before the implementation of liberalization reforms (Cf. Section 3).
-
[4]
The “Industry wage premium” is defined by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004) as the portion of worker’s wage that is not explained by observable industry and worker characteristics. It is instead related to industry affiliation. According to Cragg and Epelbaum (1996), we may cite three sources of industry rents: 1- Compensation for differences in job attributes across industries 2- Compensation for specific skills 3- Under imperfectly competitive labour market, trade protection may be a source of rent creation. If this rent is shared with workers, this may lead to industry wage differences, given the heterogeneity of the trade protection pattern across sectors.
-
[5]
Feliciano (2001) reports that almost 40% of workers in Mexican manufacturing industries were unionized. Besides, wages were set through collective bargaining at the firm or the sector level. This gives some evidences for rent sharing process in Mexico.
-
[6]
According to Hanson and Harrison (1999a), Mexico was highly protecting industries that benefit from comparative advantage. Even if such protection pattern could be unexpected, it is not exclusive to this country. Currie and Harrison (1997) show that Moroccan unskilled-labour intensive industries were relatively the most protected industries. Pavcnik et al. (2004) and Attanasio et al. (2004) report the same findings respectively for Brazil and Colombia.
-
[7]
The most common definition of the informal sector is based on the compliance with labour market legislation (minimum wage, social security contribution, firing procedures). A broader definition reported by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003, 2004) accounts temporary workers in the formal sector.
-
[8]
They also depend on the indicators used to asses the non compliance with labour market legislation.
-
[9]
The effective rate of protection is defined as the proportional increase in value added resulting from the imposition of protective measures. It measures the percentage by which value added can increase over the free trade level as a consequence of a tariff structure. The effective rate of protection captures protection of intermediate and final goods by tariff or non-tariff protective measures.
-
[10]
The transformation of non-tariffs barriers into tariff equivalent implies an increase in the nominal protection rate of industry and agriculture outputs. This coupled with a significant reduction of the nominal protection on inputs and intermediate goods lead to the rise of the effective rate of protection.
-
[11]
In appendix 1, we also report a second proxy of wage inequality, namely the annual average wage in the tertiary sector relative to that in manufacturing industries. Both ratios exhibit similar trends.
-
[12]
Institut d’économie quantitative.
-
[13]
This sector includes manufacturing industries (IAA, Agro-food industry; IME, Mechanical, electrical and electronic industry; MCCV, Pottery, glass and other non-metallic mineral industry; IC, Chemical industry; THC, Textiles, wearing apparel, leather and footwear industry; IMD), non manufacturing industries (mining, energy, electricity, water, construction) and productive services (telecom, tourism, trade, other services).
-
[14]
1997 was not included due to a large number of aberrant observations in this year.
-
[15]
Sectors considered in computing wage inequality over 1998-2002 are: IAA, IME, IC, THC, IMD, energy, tourism, transport and telecom, trade, renting.
-
[16]
According to Hanson and Harrison (1999a) the neoclassical trade theory implicitly assumes that countries protect relatively more sectors that do not benefit from comparative advantages.
-
[17]
This simple framework is potentially consistent with capital-skill complementarity. Capital is here ignored in order to simplify the model.
-
[18]
Firms are thus not able to capture rents.
-
[19]
We have applied the Mann-Whitney non-parametric test of hypothesis on the ratio WQ/WNQ in order to assess the null hypothesis of equality in variable means over two sub-periods corresponding respectively to (1975-1986) and (1987-2002) (appendix 5, table A5.1). This test rejects the null hypothesis which supports the intuition that trade liberalization exerts a significant impact on wage inequality.
-
[20]
In order to study the impact of trade openness on economic growth, Edwards (1998) regressed total factor productivity on nine trade liberalization indexes.
-
[21]
See Siroën (2001), p. 106.
-
[22]
We regress the specified equation over the following sub-periods: 1975-1998, 1983-1998 and 1998-2002. Unit root tests are performed over the period 1975-1998.
-
[23]
According to (IEQ), an important portion of EU Tunisian imports consists on intermediate goods (37%) and equipments (21%).
-
[24]
The population census carried out by (INS) in 1994 shows that women workers are relatively more educated than men: 51.4% of women workers are college or high-school graduates against 40.5% for men.
-
[25]
See Lefranc (1997), p. 1052.
-
[26]
The trade liberalization effect on wage inequality in Tunisia is nevertheless moderate relatively to that observed in some Latin American countries. The gradual implementation of trade reforms in Tunisia highly contributes to explain this fact.
-
[27]
The author wishes to thank the anonymous referees whose suggestions improved the paper greatly. The author is also grateful to Mr. Mongi Ben Chaâben from the Tunisian Institute of Quantitative economy, Mrs. Rim Ben Ayed Mouelhi, Mr. Jean-Marc Siroën, Mrs. Aude Sztulman and Mr. Mondher Ghazali for helpful comments. This paper benefited from the financial support of the French Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs and the Tunisian Ministry of higher education, scientific research and technology within the framework of the Hubert-Curien partnership program-Utique.
-
[28]
See Maurin and Parent, 1993.
1 – Introduction
1The end of the 1990s has witnessed a great deal of research on the effects of trade liberalization on wage inequality in developing countries emphasizing the debate on globalization social costs. The main studies were performed in Latin American countries, such as Mexico (Hanson and Harrison, 1999; Cragg and Epelbaum, 1996; Feliciano, 2001; Robertson, 2004), Peru (Mazumdar and Quispe-Agnoli, 2002), Chile (Beyer et al., 1999) and Colombia (Attanasio et al., 2004). Other studies focused on Asian countries such as the Asian Tigers (Wood, 1997) and India (Marjit and Acharyya, 2003; Milner et al., 2005). Papers discussing the relationship between trade openness and wage inequality in Africa are, however, relatively scarce. We can cite Görg and Ströbl (2001) for Ghana and Bigsten and Durevall (2006) for Kenya.
2An overwhelming majority of these empirical studies concluded that trade openness increases wage inequality in developing countries and highlighted different channels through which this effect is transmitted. [2] However, these conclusions appear to contradict the neoclassical trade theory prediction that increased trade with the developed countries would lead to a reduction in wage inequality in developing countries by changing goods relative prices.
3Furthermore, the scarcity of studies dedicated to African countries and, in particular, to North Africa is widely attributed to the lack of long-term data-series on wages by skill-type and on trade liberalization indicators. Such studies are, nevertheless, extremely useful for at least two reasons. The first is that they are complementary to current literature, widely focused on Latin American and Asian countries. They could improve the understanding of trade liberalization effects on wage inequality in developing countries taking into account their specific economic liberalization processes. The second reason explained by Harrison (2006) is that wage inequality is instrumental to the transmission of trade liberalization impact on poverty. Indeed, a high level of wage inequality could reduce the poverty-growth elasticity and thus, the expected results of trade liberalization reforms on poverty. Poverty alleviation being one of Africa’s top economic and social issues, a better understanding of inequality trends and channels in the continent could help better monitor, and ultimately control, poverty.
4This paper fits into this research framework. We attempt to identify the links between trade liberalization and wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers in Tunisia over the period 1975-2002. Section 2 presents a brief review of the theoretical literature. Section 3 provides a description of the Tunisian trade liberalization process as well as stylised facts on wage inequality. Section 4 presents the database used in the econometric analysis and the regression results. The Section 5 concludes. The findings reveal that an increase in imports relative to value added worsened the wage inequalities between skilled and unskilled workers over the period 1975-1998. Results also identify a negative and statistically significant relationship between Custom duties on imports and relative wages over the period 1983-1998, after the incorporation of time fixed effects. Over the period 1998-2002, while the Tunisian trade liberalization process became more active, regression results no longer identify a significant relationship between trade openness proxies and wage inequality. This is probably due to the weak number of observations related to this period. Two main categories of unskilled workers seem to be affected by trade liberalization, namely supervisors and production workers.
2 – Theoretical literature overview
5The primary theoretical reference regarding the impact of trade openness on internal wage inequalities is the Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson model or the endowment-based neoclassical theory. By assuming a world divided into two zones, the northern zone and the southern zone, and two production factors, skilled labour and unskilled labour, this model predicts that trade openness will entail in the South a decrease (increase) of the relative price of skill intensive good (unskilled-labour intensive good). This leads the South to specializing in the export of unskilled-labour intensive good and simultaneously activates to the Stolper-Samuelson effects. The Stolper-Samuelson theory (1941) stipulates that when a southern country shifts from autarky to free-trade, the factor relatively more used by the branch whose relative price increases benefits from an increase of its relative and real wage income (namely, in this case the unskilled labour). Conversely, the price of skilled labour, initially relatively higher, must decrease. The predicted consequence of liberalization for the South is therefore a reduction in wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers.
6The impact of trade liberalization on income distribution can also be analyzed through the Ricardo-Viner model or the sector-specific factors model. This model has a structure similar to the latter, since it has two goods and two factor endowments. However, it allows to distinguish between universal factors that are mobile across sectors and specific factors (ex: skilled labour and unskilled labour), which are related to certain sectors. Setting skilled (unskilled) labour as the specific factor for the skill-intensive (unskilled-labour) sector and the “general labour” as a sectors-mobile factor, this model predicts that trade liberalization leads to an increase in the relative price of unskilled-labour intensive goods in developing countries. This implies an increase (decrease) in unskilled (skilled) workers real wages, in terms of both goods. Consequences for the “general labour” are ambiguous. These workers undergo an increase in their real wage in terms of the skill-intensive good and a decrease in terms of the unskilled-labour intensive. Consequently, trade liberalization impact on this factor depends on its consumption pattern.
7Nevertheless, wage inequality deterioration observed in developing countries appears to contradict neoclassical trade theories [3] predictions. Several factors may explain the increase in skilled labour relative wages. Skill-biased technological change is particularly emphasized by the recent literature. Technological progress is skill-biased if it raises the relative demand for skilled labour at given relative factor prices (Haskel and Slaughter, 1998). Furthermore, trade liberalization and technological bias are not necessarily independent phenomena. Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004) put forward that the latter could be considered as an endogenous response to trade liberalization. Acemoglu (2003) considers that trade liberalization contributes to skill upgrading by increasing developing countries imports of machines and high technology equipments that become less expensive. To the extent that capital goods are complementary with skilled labour, we may expect an increase in the relative demand of the latter. Pissarides (1997) also developed a model where trade liberalization allows Southern firms to boost their imports in capital goods from Northern countries. This would consequently enhance the incentives to learn and imitate new technologies, which contributes to raise the relative demand for skilled workers.
8The decrease of unskilled workers relative wages could be also induced by a reduction in the industry wage premium [4] such as reported by Currie and Harrison (1997), Feliciano (2001) and Cragg and Epelbaum (1996). Indeed, under the assumption of imperfect competition, it may well be the case that some “high-protected” industries benefit from quasi-rents that are shared with workers, due for example to a high union power. [5] In case of labour market rigidity, the adjustment to trade liberalization of these industries would be predominantly made through wages, therefore implying a reduction in the premium. Besides, if the concerned industries are mostly unskilled-labour intensive, then one would expect a deepening of wage inequality. [6]
9The effect of the outsourcing of intermediate goods production on wage inequality was highlighted by Feenstra and Hanson (1996, 1997). Indeed, trade liberalization and foreign direct investment allow for part of the intermediate goods production to be relocated from developed countries to developing countries. By Northern technological standards, these goods are considered unskilled-labour intensive. Inversely, in Southern countries, they are considered skill-intensive goods. Thus, outsourcing contributes to skill upgrading. This leads indirectly to increase wage inequality. More generally, the off shoring of some steps of the production process as well as activities related to the tertiary sector (call centres, hotlines and back office services) by Northern firms contributes to the increase of the relative demand of skilled labour in host countries (Kirkegaard, 2007 for India).
10From this perspective, Zhu and Trefler (2005) proposed an alternative to the HOS model by combining HOS and Ricardian international technology differences frameworks. According to this model, if the South undergoes a technological ‘catch-up’ process, this implies a migration of the least skill-intensive Northern goods in the South where they become the most skill-intensive goods. The relative demand of skilled workers as well as wage inequality rise in both regions. This is due to the destruction of unskilled-intensive jobs in the North and the creation of skill-intensive jobs in the South. This mechanism is related to that described by Feenstra and Hanson (1996).
11According to Wood (1997), the access to the global market of large low-income countries such as Bangladesh, China, India, Indonesia, and Pakistan would alter middle-income countries comparative advantages. Indeed, the latter appear to have relatively more abundant skilled labour than the former. The increase in the relative price of unskilled-labour intensive goods, and thus the expected Stolper Samuelson effects become uncertain in emerging countries.
12The informal sector [7] could offer an additional adjustment mechanism to import competing domestic firms. In order to reduce their costs, firms exposed to foreign competition may indeed attempt to circumvent labour market legislation by subcontracting some of their activities to small, informal firms or by hiring temporary workers, (Attanasio et al., 2004; Goldberg and Pavcnik, 2003; Currie and Harrison, 1997). If unskilled workers are relatively more employed in the informal sector (Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003) for Colombia) and that, at given skill level, informal sector workers are less paid than those of the formal sector (Attanasio et al. (2004) for Colombia and Pavcnik et al. (2004) for Brazil), one may expect trade-induced expansion of the informal sector to deteriorate the relative wage income of unskilled workers. However, results given by empirical studies related to the impact of trade liberalization on the probability of working in the informal sector are mitigated and depend on the rigidity of the labour market. [8] Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003), for example, don’t identify a significant relationship between informality and tariffs barriers reduction in Brazil, where the labour market is considered to be relatively flexible. In Columbia, this relationship is positive but only over the period preceding labour market deregulation reforms that were introduced in the 1990s. Indeed, these reforms are considered by Kugler (1999) as contributing to formal employment increase in Columbia. Thus, labour market institutions intervene in trade liberalization impact on the informal sector.
13However, Maloney (2004) diverges with the traditional view that considers the informal sector as an opportunity to by-pass labour market regulations, especially when it deals with low-wages countries lacking strong union power. Indeed, the author highlights the weak portion (20%) of informal Mexican companies involved in subcontracting business and stresses its decrease during the trade liberalization episode. Instead, he suggests considering the informal sector as an unregulated micro entrepreneurial sector chosen by voluntary self-employed workers.
3 – Tunisian trade liberalization process
14Tunisia implemented until the first half of the 1980s an import substitution policy characterised by regulatory government interventionism in price setting, private investments and banking system. In 1986, an economic crisis led to the initiation of a structural adjustment plan, instigated by international financial institutions. Numerous actions were taken to re-establish the market forces, deregulate the domestic market and lower tariff and non tariff barriers. Trade liberalization was one of he most important reforms.
15During the 1990s, the Tunisian trade process was marked by the signature of the GATT agreements in 1990 followed by the adherence to the WTO and the signature of the EUROMED agreements, in 1995. These agreements imply the establishment of a free trade zone including the majority of industrial products over a period of 12 years while the GATT affiliation entails the reduction of tariffs and non-tariffs barriers.
16As shown in table 1, the period 1986-1990 exhibits an important reduction in the effective rate of protection. [9] The Sachs and Warner (1995) Openness index classifies Tunisia as an open economy starting from 1989. Then, from 1990 to 1997, the effective rate of protection increased due to the transformation of non tariff barriers, mainly applied to final consumption goods, into tariff equivalent. [10] The trade liberalization process became more active after 1997 as the effective rate of protection decreases from 71% to 49% in 2002.
The ERP* in Tunisian manufacturing and non manufacturing industries, 1980-2002
The ERP* in Tunisian manufacturing and non manufacturing industries, 1980-2002
4 – Stylised facts on wage inequality in Tunisia
17The following analysis of the evolution of wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers in Tunisia aims to identify the episodes of trend return. For this purpose, we adopt a wage inequality standard measure which is the relative annual average wage of skilled workers, (Feenstra and Hanson, 1997; Hanson and Harrison, 1999; Robertson, 2004). [11]
4.1 – Data sources
18Data on wages as well as the variables used in the empirical analysis are taken from the database on wages (1998) provided by the Quantitative Economic Institute (IEQ, Tunis). [12] It is to our knowledge the only source of data available in Tunisia in relation to sector wages that offers a distinction between the different skill categories (Engineers and senior executives, supervisors, employees, workers and apprentices). These data combine results of industrial activities surveys (1969-1981) and National surveys on economic activity (1983-1996) carried out by the Tunisian Institute of Statistics (INS), as well as results of studies by the Tunisian Ministry of Social Affairs.
19Given the importance of studying the episode following 1998, that witnessed a relatively important reduction of effective protection in Tunisia, it was necessary to extend our observation period. The only available data for this purpose are firm level data provided by the national annual survey report on firms conducted by the (INS) over the period 1997-2002. The main advantage of this database is that it offers a distribution of the workforce according to the skill level. However, it has the inconvenience of not providing a similar decomposition of the firm total wage bill. In order to desegregate wage data, we adopted a method applied by Maurin and Parent (1993). Details are presented in appendix 2.
4.2 – The measure of wage inequality using the ratio
20Table 2 reports trends in the relative average annual wage of skilled workers belonging to the non agricultural productive sector [13] over the period 1975-1998. Skilled workers are here related to the category “engineers and senior executives”. Unskilled workers are “supervisors“, “employees“, “factory workers“ and “apprentices“. Wage inequality is measured by relative wages.
Annual nominal average wages
Annual nominal average wages
21Figure 1 shows that the 1970s and the first half of the 1980s were characterised by a reduction in wage inequality in the Tunisian non-agricultural productive sector. A skilled worker was paid in 1975 almost four times the wage of an unskilled worker. In 1985, the relative wages ratio is about 3. This ratio increased after 1986 reaching 3.42 in 1991. During the following years, wage inequality displays a slight decrease as it reduces to 3.27 in 1998. The decreasing trend in wage inequality was therefore interrupted at the implementation of the trade liberalization process.
Wage inequality in Tunisia, 1975-2002
Wage inequality in Tunisia, 1975-2002
22Table 3 presents the evolution of wage inequality over the period 1998-2002 [14] on the basis of firm-level database. Comparison with table 1 is not possible, given the differences in sectors included in relative wages computation. [15] We may notice an important relative increase in wage inequality between 2001 and 2002 (+20%), after a relative stagnation and a decrease between 1999 and 2001 of this ratio. The second plot entitled “inequality 2” in figure 1 allows us to examine relative wages movements between over the period 1998-2002.
Wage inequality
Wage inequality
23In order to make some robustness checks on wage inequality trend over the period 1975-1998, we try to explore the evolution of the average wage of engineers and senior executives relative to the average wage of the different subcategories of unskilled workers. Figures A3.1 to A3.7 (appendix 3) confirm previous observations. The decreasing trend of the different indicators computed is interrupted over the second half of the 1980s. An increase is noted then, until the first half of the 1990s, followed by a relative stagnation. It is important to emphasize that between 1975 and 1980, the average wage of skilled workers relative to that of supervisors sets apart from the general decreasing trend by rising by almost 9%. These findings are also discernible in the figure that plots the internal wage inequalities within the categories of unskilled workers. The average wage of the various subcategories of unskilled workers relative to the average wage of the most unskilled one which is “apprentices”, is constant over the observation period which implies a perfect substitution between these workers, with the exception of the supervisors in the first half of the 1980s.
24Overall, it appears that the increase in wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers over the period 1986-1991 coincides with a relatively important decrease in the effective rate of protection (from 70% to 44%). Table 1 shows that trade reforms pattern was not uniform across manufacturing industries. For instance, the food-processing and textile industries that benefited from a relatively higher protection level prior to trade liberalization observe a decrease of their effective protection rates by about 300% and 200% respectively. Within the same period, the construction materials, glass and ceramics industry (from 40% to 82%), the electrical and mechanical industries (from 88% to 101%), and the chemical industries (from 88% to 78%) underwent either an intensification of their rate of protection, or a minor decrease. As the unskilled-labour intensive industries seem to be the most affected by the openness shock, this may contribute to clarify the increase in wage inequality in Tunisia between 1986 and 1991 after trade reforms implementation. [16]
25Over the period 1991-1998, the absence of important movements in relative wages could be explained by the increase of Tunisia’s effective protection rate. An examination of wage inequality trend after 1998 reveals the resumption of wage inequality increase in 2002, coupled with a significant decrease of trade protection.
26Figures 2 to 5 allow to assess the evolution of wage inequality relatively to trade liberalization proxies, such as custom duties on imports (DD/M), imports and exports on sector value added (M/VA, X/VA), and the effective rate of protection of the Tunisian domestic market (ERP). The increase in wage inequality over the second half of the 1980s is coupled with a relatively important decline in the DD/M ratio and the (ERP) that reflects the trade protection level. This increase also coincides with the increase in the X/VA ratio and the M/VA ratio (with some delay). The relative stagnation of relative wages in the mid-1990s corresponds to a moderate evolution of trade indictors.
Wage inequality and trade openness (DD_M *)
Wage inequality and trade openness (DD_M *)
* The indicator DD_M is the ratio on customs duties to imports. WQ_WNQ is the relative wage of skilled workers.Wage inequality and trade openness (M_VA*)
Wage inequality and trade openness (M_VA*)
* The indicator M_VA is the ratio on imports to value added. WQ_WNQ is the relative wage of skilled workers.Trade openness and wage inequality (ERP*)
Trade openness and wage inequality (ERP*)
* The indicator ERP is the effective rate of protection. WQ_WNQ is the relative wage of skilled workers.Wage inequality and trade openness in Tunisia (X_VA*)
Wage inequality and trade openness in Tunisia (X_VA*)
* The indicator X_VA is the ratio on exports to total value added. WQ_WNQ is the relative wage of skilled workers5 – Empirical analysis and data overview
27The first subsection presents the econometric model and the data set used. The second displays the empirical results.
5.1 – Theoretical model and data overview
28We consider the following constant elasticity of substitution production function (CES) with two labour inputs, [17] namely skilled labour (LQ) and unskilled labour (LNQ). This approach is also adopted by Katz and Murphy (1992), Katz and Autor (1999) and Autor et al. (2008).
30where:
31Y: aggregate output;
32LQ and LNQ: skilled and unskilled labour;
33at and bt: parameters representing skilled an unskilled augmenting technical change;
34?: indexes the share of work activities of skilled labour;
35?: a parameter that determines the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labour.
36Hicks-neutral technological progress implies a proportionate increase in the parameters at and bt. “Intensive” skill-biased technological changes involve increases in at/bt as defined by Johnson and Stafford (1998). An increase in ? entails “extensive” skill-biased technological changes. Changes in these technical parameters could also represent, according to Katz and Autor (1999), non-neutral effects on skill groups of changes in the relative prices or quantities of non labour inputs such as capital and shifts in the product demand among industries with different skill intensities.
37We suppose perfect competition in goods and labour markets. [18] Assuming that skilled and unskilled workers are paid their marginal product we can use equation (1) to solve for the ratio of marginal products of the two types of labour, yielding a relationship between relative wages in year and relative supplies in year given by equations (4) and (5).
39Expressed in logarithmic form, equation (4) becomes:
41This can be rewritten as:
43where: indexes relative demand shifts favouring skilled workers.
44Changes in relative wages are thus the result of changes in the relative supply and demand of skilled labour. The greater the elasticity of substitution ? between the two skill groups and the smaller the impact of shifts in relative supplies on relative wages, the greater must be fluctuations in demand shifts (Dt). Changes in Dt can occur due to skill biased technological change, non-neutral changes in the relative prices or quantities of non-labour inputs and shifts in product demand either from domestic or international fluctuations.
45Implementing an empirical version of equation (6), Katz and Autor (1999) propose to replace the unobserved time series Dt by a time trend and/or relative demand movement’s proxies, such as cyclical indicators or international trade measures. As our main objective is to investigate trade liberalization effects on relative wages in Tunisia, we choose to estimate a specification of equation (6) that substitutes Dt by measures of international trade (we introduce lags to account for inertia effects) and the growth rates of unemployment and GDP that capture labour market cyclical fluctuations. As Autor et al. (2008), we also incorporate real minimum wages allowing to account for institutional effects. Estimated equation is presented as follows:
47where:
- i: represents the sectors;
- t: represents the year;
- ?it: Random disturbances.
48The trade openness proxies used in the empirical analysis don’t benefit from a general consensus regarding their relevance. Highlighting the difficulty to conceive a perfectly satisfactory openness measure, Edwards (1998) suggests different proxies as robustness checks. [20] Thus, in order to measure trade liberalization, this paper uses three proxies. The first two are the ratios of exports and imports relative to sector value added, namely X/VA and M/VA that are available for all sectors throughout the observation period. These indicators of exposure and dependency on foreign trade do not necessarily reflect, however, the trade policy strategy of the country and suffer from an economic and econometric endogeneity problem (Edwards, 1998; Pritchett, 1996; Goldberg and Pavcnik, 2004). The third indicator DD/M computed as the custom duties on imports allows to better capture the trade protection policy (Edwards, 1992). This ratio is, however only available over the period 1983-2002.
49We would have preferred to use the effective protection rate as a fourth indicator. This measure presents at least two advantages as emphasized by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004) in their discussion on tariffs. The first is that ERP changes during trade liberalization reform episodes are not sector-uniform. It would have enabled us to distinguish the effects of trade reforms from other economic reforms. The second advantage is that ERP movements in Tunisia during the 1980s, as in many other developing countries such as Brazil and Columbia, result from a governmental decision to fulfil the GATT and WTO directives. This would have had the effect of minimising the endogeneity risk. This measure is, however, only available for manufacturing industries over the period 1983-1998 and suffer from many shortcomings. It also would have been appropriate to use a measure of non-tariff barriers, as emphasized by Siroën (2001). Such indicator may account for the decline of quantitative restrictions. [21] Indeed, Mouelhi (2007) reports that the share of imports subject to licenses decreased from 94% before 1986 to 30% in 1991. This decreasing trend is also observed in the 1990s. Unfortunately, long time series on non-tariffs barriers are not available. All of the indicators were provided by the IEQ. We incorporate sector fixed effects to take into account the unobservable sector heterogeneity as well as time fixed effects to capture macroeconomic shocks and other unobservable determinants of wage inequalities.
5.2 – Empirical results
50We start by applying the Hausman test in order to choose between fixed effects and random effects estimation. If individual random effects are correlated with the regressors, random effects model estimates are biased and fixed effect estimator is the best unbiased linear estimator. Despite our relatively limited observation period, we apply specific panel data unit root tests (appendix 5, table A5.2). [22] Results reveal that all series are clearly stationary, with the exception of X/VA that is integrated of order 1. Thus, we include this variable in the regression equation in first differenced form. Hausman test results allow us to choose the random effects estimator.
51Columns 1 to 3 of table 4 present estimation results for the period 1975-1998. An increase in imports relative to sector value-added is likely to amplify wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. This result is quite unexpected as increased trade openness is supposed to reduce wage inequality, according to the neoclassical trade theory of exchanges. This finding could, however, be explained by Tunisian imports structure. Indeed, intermediate goods and equipments constitute a large share of Tunisian imports. [23] They are then transformed and assembled in offshore and re-exported. To the extent that they are complementary to skilled labour, one may expect that they contribute to increase the relative demand of skilled workers and thus, indirectly raise wage inequality. Such result points out the limits of the HOS model, which confines trade exchanges on final consumption goods. The outsourcing of intermediate goods production (Feenstra and Hanson, 1997) or the easier access of developing countries to imported capital goods (Acemoglu, 2003), constitute trade-induced explanations of the positive and statistically significant relationship between imports and wage inequality. The coefficient on exports relative to value-added is statistically insignificant. These results are robust to the inclusion of sector and time fixed effects (see Columns 3-4) and to changes in the estimation period (1983-1998) (see Columns 5 and 6). We also incorporate the ratio on custom duties relative to imports. Controlling for sector fixed effects, we find a negative and statistically significant relationship (at 5% level) between this variable and wage inequality (see Column 8). Hence, over the period 1983-1998, a reduction in tariffs barriers implies a deepening of wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. This result converges with the findings of many previous studies on wage inequality in developing countries. However, it raises doubts on the relevance of HOS predictions. Over the period 1998-2002, while the trade liberalization process exhibits a particular strengthening, results do not indicate a statistically significant relationship between openness proxies and relative wages. This could be due to the insufficient number of corresponding observations.
52The coefficient on the relative supply of skilled labour is counter-intuitively positive over the 1975-1998 period (see Column 3). It becomes insignificant when it interacts with a dummy variable taking the value of 1, over the years following the initiation of trade liberalization reforms (see Column 4). Over the period 1998-2002, this coefficient is negative and statistically significant implying an elasticity of substitution of about , as shown in Column 10. However, this result is not robust to openness proxies changes. The role of minimum wages and labour market cyclical conditions are also investigated. An increase in the real minimum wage yields to compress wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. Furthermore, the impact of unemployment growth on the evolution of relative wages is likely to be insignificant. Overall, the different regressions underline the central role of trade liberalization in rising wage inequality through skill upgrading.
Regression results
Regression results
5.3 – Sensitivity tests
53Regressing the model using as a dependent variable the ratio on “engineers and senior executives” annual wage relative to those of unskilled workers subcategories reveals that supervisors and factory workers are the main categories affected by trade liberalization reforms (see table 5). Trade induced-technological changes may play an important role in such a trend by favouring engineers and executives relatively to intermediate skills and by modernizing production processes so as to free the most unskilled workers.
Sensitivity tests, 1975-1998
Sensitivity tests, 1975-1998
5.4 – Robustness tests
54We check results in table 6. We increase the number of lags on trade openness variables to three (see Columns 1 and 4). We also attempt to assess the results relative to the absence of a significant relationship between skilled labour relative supply and relative wages, by substituting the former using the sector workers average education years (Nme). The share of women in the active population is also introduced as an additional control variable. Indeed, women labour supply in Tunisia is sensitive to economic conditions and is generally considered as a flexible workforce. Finally, we attempt to explore the effect of sector capital intensity on relative wages, which allows to indirectly assess the capital-skill complementarity hypothesis (see Columns 3, 6 and 7). Results confirm the significant impact of trade openness and minimum wages on wage inequality in Tunisia, over the observation periods including 1998-2002 (see Column 8). The statistically insignificance of the coefficient on sector workers average education years supports the previous finding regarding the lack of a dominant role of relative supply in wage inequality movements. Over the period 1983-1998, a high rate of unemployment growth would have contributed to increase relative wages. Unemployment is thus likely to have mainly affected unskilled workers over this period. Women labour supply impacts negatively relative wages, leading to the narrowing of wage inequality [24] (see Column 5). This may be due to the clear improvement of their education level since the second half of the 1980s. However, this result is not robust to changes in regression periods.
Robustness checks
Robustness checks
5.5 – Endogeneity tests
55Given the possible endogeneity of the relative supply variable LQ/LNQ that could bias regression results and yields to the positive counter-intuitive coefficient reported in Column 3 of table 4, we chose to instrument this variable using the double least squares estimator. Instruments used over the period 1975-1998 are the lagged values of the variable related to sector workers average education years. Over the period 1983-1998, we use lagged values of sector value-added.
56Table 7 displays the results of the Sargan over-identification test that does not reject the validity of the instruments. The Hausman test rejects the double least squares estimates in favour of ordinary least squares estimates. Therefore, it does not support the relative supply endogeneity hypothesis.
Endogeneity tests
Endogeneity tests
57Two main comments arise from our findings. The first is relative to the positive, significant and relatively robust relationship between trade liberalization and wage inequality in Tunisia, over the periods 1975-1998 and 1983-1998. An increase of 10% of imports relative to the sector value-added contributes to raise relative wages by about 2.5%. Similarly, a reduction of 10% in tariff protection over 1983-1998 increases wage inequality by 5%.
58Results are likely to refute the neoclassical trade theory predictions for developing countries. However, they converge with the conclusions of Latin American empirical country-studies. Numerous channels may trigger such a result. The first is the protection pattern prior to trade liberalization, which, contrary to HOS model hypotheses, favoured unskilled-labour intensive sectors. These sectors were from the second half of the 1980s the most affected by trade reforms. They may have seen a dissipation of the quasi-rent induced by protectionism. Trade-induced skill-biased technological and organisational progress plays also an important role in wage inequality through its effects on skill upgrading.
59The second observation is relative to the importance of the demand shifts in relative wages movements, whereas relative supply does not appear to have a significant effect. This result could reflect a supply measurement problem. Indeed, the relative employment variable that is generally used in neoclassical models assuming full employment becomes inadequate when we account for the Tunisian structural unemployment rate of 16%. Therefore, the wage inequality trend does not reflect here “the competitive adjustment of wages to labour supply and demand shocks for different types of labour. Instead, it highlights the institutional forces leading the labour market”. [25]
60The excess of skilled labour supply, coupled with an upward trend of wage inequality, although moderate, is primarily seen as a paradox and may reveal a restriction of skilled workers demand to preserve economic rents. However, the explanation is essentially related to the inadequacy of some university academic programs with firms’ requirements. Unskilled workers unemployment could be induced by institutional wage rigidities as well as by firms’ adjustment response to trade liberalization shock.
6 – Conclusion
61In the 1990s, an abundant literature investigated the link between the integration into the world economy and income inequalities. It was primarily dedicated to Latin American developing countries. The increase in wage inequality reported by these studies is likely to contradict the neoclassical trade theory predictions. Trade liberalization contributes to such a phenomenon through different channels. We can cite the increase in some occupation returns that require a high education level, the role of production relocation for intermediate goods, skill-biased technological changes, the dissipation of quasi-rents and the expansion of the informal sector.
62This paper attempted to identify, using panel data, the nature of the relationship between trade liberalization initiated in Tunisia from the second half of the 1980s and wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers, over the period 1975-2002. It, thus, aimed to extend wage inequality studies to North African countries where related studies are relatively scarce. This first investigation highlights the necessity to explore further channels through which the impact of trade liberalization could be transmitted.
63The descriptive analysis performed in Section 3 reveals an increase in wage inequality after the implementation of trade liberalization reforms in 1986. This trend is particularly noticeable [26] over 1986-1990 as well as in 2002; periods exhibiting a significant decline of the rate of trade protection. As Katz and Murphy (1992), Katz and Autor (1999) and Autor et al. (2008), we assumed a (CES) production function with two labour inputs, skilled (LQ) and unskilled (LNQ) labour. We proxy the skilled labour relative demand using trade liberalization measures, instead of a time trend in previous studies. Regression results confirm the existence of a positive and statistically significant relationship between imports relative to value-added and wage inequality over the period 1975-1998. The decline in trade protection measured by custom duties relative to imports DD/M contributes to the increase of wage inequality over the period 1983-1998. The main unskilled workers subcategories that seem to be affected by trade liberalization are supervisors and manufactory workers. Between 1998 and 2002, estimation results do not allow us to identify a statistically significant relationship between the openness proxies and relative wages. Furthermore, a decrease in real minimum wages is likely to exert an increasing pressure on wage inequality, though moderate.
64Further studies based on firm level data would allow for a better understanding of the relationship between trade openness and wage inequality in Tunisia by investigating transmission channels as skill-biased technological progress or industry rent dissipation. The objective is to consider the trade liberalization impact on wage inequalities as resulting from different phenomena endogenous to this process.
The alternative measure of wage inequality
66Indicator: the ratio of the average wage in the tertiary sector to the average wage in the manufacturing industry
Appendix 1.1 – 1978-1998
Annual nominal average wages
Annual nominal average wages
Ratio* of the average wage in the tertiary sector to the average wage in the manufacturing industry, 1975-2002
Ratio* of the average wage in the tertiary sector to the average wage in the manufacturing industry, 1975-2002
* WSCES_WIMFAppendix 1.2 – 1998-2002
Ratio of the annual average wage
Ratio of the annual average wage
Firm total wage bill [28]
67We define the following variables:
- CS: total wage bill in firm i;
- L: total employment in firm i;
- j: index corresponding to qualification type;
- Lj employment corresponding to category j;
- J qualification type chosen as reference;
- lj category j’s share in total employment;
- WB average wage bill per worker in firm i;
- WBj average wage bill for the category j;
68In addition, category j’s share in total employment could be expressed as:
69Total wage bill in firm I could be presented as follows:
70Similarly, average wage bill per worker in firm i could be specified as:
72Hence, we obtain the following expression: .
73The current database provides firm data on total wage bill, as well as skilled and unskilled workers employment. Unskilled workers are considered as our category of reference. Assuming that Q indexes the skilled workers category and NQ the unskilled workers category, we obtain the following expression of the average individual wage bill relative to a firm i:
75This yields to the estimation of the following random coefficient model:
77Using the Swamy’s estimator, we obtain for each firm, average individual wage bills corresponding to each category of workers for the entire period 1998-2002. Then, multiplying them by the corresponding workers’ numbers available for each year, we find skilled and unskilled total wage bills, for each company of the sample and each year of observation.
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Unskilled workers category: supervisorsNote: WQ, average annual wage for executive managers and engineers; WAM, average annual wage for supervisors.
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Unskilled workers category: employeesNote: WQ, average annual wage for executive managers and engineers; WEMP, average annual wage for employees.
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Unskilled workers category: factory workersNote: WQ, average annual wage for executive managers and engineers; WOUV, average annual wage for factory workers.
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Wage inequality in Tunisia
Unskilled workers category: apprenticesNote: WQ, average annual wage for executive managers and engineers; WMAN, average annual wage for apprentices.
Real wages evolution for sub-categories of unskilled workers
Real wages evolution for sub-categories of unskilled workers
Note: CSUP, executive managers and engineers; MAN, apprentices; AM, supervisors; EMP, employees; OUV, factory workers.Wage inequality between sub-categories
Wage inequality between sub-categories
Reference category: apprenticesNote: CSUP, executive managers and engineers; MAN, apprentices; AM, supervisors; EMP: employees; OUV: factory workers.
Annual real minimum wage evolution in Tunisia
Annual real minimum wage evolution in Tunisia
Two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum (Mann-Whitney) test
Two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum (Mann-Whitney) test
Panel data specific unit root tests
Panel data specific unit root tests
Bibliographie
References
- Acemoglu, D., 2003. Patterns of skill premia, Review of Economic studies 70, 199-230.
- Attanasio, O., Goldberg, P., Pavcnik, N., 2004. Trade reforms and wage inequality in Colombia, Journal of development Economics 74, 331-366.
- Autor, D., Lawrence, H., Katz, F., Kearney, M., 2008. Trends in U.S wage inequality: Revising the revisionists, Review of Economics and Statistics 90(2), 300-23, May.
- Ben Slama, M., Boumediene, M., 2003. L’exportation manufacturière tunisienne et le contenu éducatif de l’emploi, une analyse en termes de motricité intersectorielle, in « Compétitivité, croissance et ouverture économique : enjeux et défis », proceedings of the conference held in Tunis, October, 23-24, 2003, 30th anniversary of the IEQ, Cahiers de l’IEQ, special issue.
- Beyer, H., Vergara, V., 1999. Trade liberalization and wage inequality, Journal of Development Economics 59, 103-23.
- Bigsten, A., Durevall, D., 2006. Openness and wage inequality in Kenya, 1964-2000, World Development 34(3), 465-80, March.
- Boudhiaf, M., 2001. La politique tunisienne d’ouverture commerciale, in Siroën, J.-M., Boudhiaf, M,, Ouverture et développement économique, Paris: Economica, 309-20.
- Cragg, I., Epelbaum, M., 1996. Why has wage dispersion grown in Mexico? Is it the incidence of reforms or the growing demand for skills?, Journal of Development Economics 51, 99-116.
- Currie, J., Harrison, A., 1997. Sharing the costs: The impact of trade reform on capital and labour in Morocco, Journal of Labour Economics 15(3), 44-72.
- Durevall, D., Munshi, F., 2006. Trade liberalization and wage inequality: Empirical evidence from Bangladesh, Working Paper in Economics 241, Goteborg University.
- Edwards, S., 1992. Trade orientation, distortions and growth in developing countries, Journal of Development Economics 39(1), 31-58.
- Edwards, S., 1998. Openness, productivity and growth: What do we really know?, The Economic Journal 108(447), 383-98, March.
- Feenstra, R., Hanson, G., 1996. Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative wages, in Feenstra, R., Grossman, G., Irwin, D., (Eds.), Political Economy of Trade Policy: Essays in Honour of Jaghdish Bhagwati, MIT press, Cambridge, 89-127.
- Feenstra, R., Hanson, G., 1997. Foreign direct investment and relative wages: Evidence from Mexico’s maquiladoras, Journal of International Economics 42, 371-93.
- Feliciano, Z., 2001. Workers and trade liberalization: The impact of trade reforms in Mexico on wages and employment, Industrial and Labour Relations Review 55(1), 95-115.
- Geishecker, I., Holger, G., 2004. International outsourcing and wages: Winners and losers, mimeo, www. etsg. org/ ETSG2004/ Papers/ Geishecker. pdf.
- Goldberg, P., Pavcnik, N., 2003. The response of the informal sector to trade liberalization, NBER Working Paper 9443, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
- Goldberg, P., Pavcnik, N., 2004. Trade, inequality and poverty: What do we know?, NBER Working Paper 10593, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
- Goldberg, P., Pavcnik, N., 2005. Trade, wages and the political economy of trade protection: Evidence from the Colombian trade reforms, Journal of International Economics 66, 75-105.
- Görg, H., Ströbl, E., 2001. Relative wages, openness and skill-biased technological change in Ghana, Credit Research Paper 01/18, University of Nottingham.
- Grossman, G., Rossi-Hansberg, E., 2006. The rise of offshoring: It’s not wine for cloth anymore, paper presented at Kansas Fed’s Jackson Hole conference for central bankers, http:// www. kc. frb. org.
- Haouas, I., Yagoubi., M., 2001. Conséquences de l’ouverture sur le marché du travail : le cas tunisien, in Siroën, J.-M., Boudhiaf, M., Ouverture et développement économique, Paris: Economica, 322-40.
- Hanson, G., Harrison., A., 1999a. Trade liberalization and wage inequality in Mexico, Industrial and Labour Relations Review 52(2), 271-88.
- Hanson, G., Harrison., A., 1999b. Who gains from trade reform? Some remaining puzzles, Journal of Economic Development 59, 125-54.
- Harrison, A., (Ed), 2006. Globalization and Poverty, The University of Chicago Press.
- Haskel, J., Slaughter., M., 1998. Does the sector bias of skill-biased technical change explain changing wage inequality?, NBER Working Paper 6565, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
- Institut d’Économie Quantitative, 1998. Les Cahiers de l’IEQ 5, Ministère du développement économique, Tunis, mars.
- Institut d’Économie Quantitative, 2002. Les Cahiers de l’IEQ 16, Ministère du développement économique, Tunis, mars.
- Institut d’Économie Quantitative, 2003. Les Cahiers de l’IEQ 17, Ministère du développement économique, Tunis, mars.
- Johnson, G., Stafford., F., 1998. Technology regimes and the distribution of real wages, in Greene, C., Eliasson, G. (Eds.), Microfoundations of Economic Growth: A Schumpeterian Perspective, University of Michigan Press.
- Katz, L., Kevin, M., Murphy, K., 1992. Changes in relative wages, 1963-87: Supply and demand factors, Quarterly Journal of Economics 10, 35-78.
- Kirkegaard, J., 2007. Offshoring, outsourcing and production-relocation labour market effects in OECD countries and developing Asia, Working Paper series WP 07-2, the Peterson Institute for International Economics, April.
- Kugler, A., 1999. The impact of firing costs on turnover and unemployment: Evidence from the Colombian labour market reforms, International Tax and Public Finance 6, 389-410.
- Lahouel, M., Marouani, M., 2003. Les accords euro-méditerranéens : les enseignements du cas tunisien, séminaire EMMA-RINOS, « Analyse comparatiste des processus d’intégration régionale Nord-Sud », Paris, 26-27 mai.
- Leamer, E., 1994. Trade, wages and revolving door ideas, NBER Working Paper 4716, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
- Lefranc, A., 1997. Salaires et relatifs et chômage, une analyse comparative France/États-Unis, Revue économique 48(5), 1041-60.
- Machin, S., Van Reenen, J., 2007. Changes in wage inequality, special paper 18, Centre of economic performance, the Economic and Social Research Council, April.
- Maloney, F., 2004. Informality revisited, World Development 32(7), 1159-78.
- Marjit, S., Acharyya, R., 2003. International Trade, Wage Inequality and the Developing Economy: A General Equilibrium Approach, Heidelberg.
- Maurin, E., Parent, M.-C., 1993. Productivité et coût du travail par qualifications, in Croissance, emploi, productivité, proceedings, 18ème journée des centrales de bilans, Association Française des Centrales de bilans (AFCB), Paris, 23 novembre.
- Mazumdar, J., Quispe-Agnoli, M., 2002. Trade and the skill premium in developing countries: The role of intermediate goods and some evidence from Peru, Working Paper 2002-11, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, July.
- Mouelhi Ben Ayed, R., 2007. Impact of trade liberalization on firm’s labour demand by skill: The case of Tunisian manufacturin, Labour Economics 14(3), 539-63, June.
- Pavcnik, N., 2003. What explains skill upgrading in less developed countries?, Journal of Development Economics 71, 311-28.
- Pavcnik, N., Blom, A., Goldberg, P., Schady, N., 2004. Liberalization and industry wage structure: Evidence from Brazil, The World Bank Economic Review 18(3).
- Pissarides, C., 1997. Learning by trading and the returns to human capital in developing countries, The World Bank Economic Review 11, 17-32.
- Pritchett, L., 1996. Measuring outward orientation in LDCs: Can it be done?, Journal of Development Economics 49(2), 307-35.
- Redjeb, M., Ghobentini, S., 2005. L’intermédiation sur le marché du travail en Tunisie, Cahiers de la stratégie de l’emploi 2005/19, Unité Recherches et analyses sur l’emploi, Département Stratégie en matière d’emploi, Organisation internationale du travail.
- Robertson, R., 2004. Relative prices and wage inequality: Evidence from Mexico, Journal of International Economics 64, 387-409.
- Sachs, J., Warner, A., 1995. Economic reforms and the process of global integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 25th anniversary issue, 1-118.
- Siröen, J.-M., 2001. L’ouverture commerciale est-elle mesurable ?, in Ouverture et développement économique, proceedings, CNRS, GDR Economie & Finance internationales (11th conference, 2000), Paris: Economica, 103-23.
- Wood, A., 1995. How trade hurt unskilled workers?, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(3), 57-80.
- Wood, A., 1997. Openness and wage inequality in developing countries, The Latin American challenge to East Asian conventional wisdom, The World Bank Economic Review 11(1), 33-57.
- Zhu, S., Trefler, D., 2005. Trade and inequality in developing countries: A general equilibrium analysis, Journal of International Economics 65, 21-48.
Mots-clés éditeurs : ouverture commerciale, Tunisie, inégalités de salaires
Date de mise en ligne : 19/10/2009.
https://doi.org/10.3917/ecoi.117.0063Notes
-
[1]
Monia Ghazali, Lecturer, laboratoire LEDA, Université Paris Dauphine (moniaghazali@ yahoo. fr).
-
[2]
Studies refer to the role of FDI, outsourcing, skill-biased technological change, the increase of the returns to education, the extension of the informal sector due to trade reforms…
-
[3]
We should note that Tunisia as other North African countries observes a paradox related to the high level of college graduates unemployment. The neoclassical trade theory does not involve such hypothesis. Furthermore, the majority of developing countries did not experience a uniform trade protection pattern across sectors, before the implementation of liberalization reforms (Cf. Section 3).
-
[4]
The “Industry wage premium” is defined by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004) as the portion of worker’s wage that is not explained by observable industry and worker characteristics. It is instead related to industry affiliation. According to Cragg and Epelbaum (1996), we may cite three sources of industry rents: 1- Compensation for differences in job attributes across industries 2- Compensation for specific skills 3- Under imperfectly competitive labour market, trade protection may be a source of rent creation. If this rent is shared with workers, this may lead to industry wage differences, given the heterogeneity of the trade protection pattern across sectors.
-
[5]
Feliciano (2001) reports that almost 40% of workers in Mexican manufacturing industries were unionized. Besides, wages were set through collective bargaining at the firm or the sector level. This gives some evidences for rent sharing process in Mexico.
-
[6]
According to Hanson and Harrison (1999a), Mexico was highly protecting industries that benefit from comparative advantage. Even if such protection pattern could be unexpected, it is not exclusive to this country. Currie and Harrison (1997) show that Moroccan unskilled-labour intensive industries were relatively the most protected industries. Pavcnik et al. (2004) and Attanasio et al. (2004) report the same findings respectively for Brazil and Colombia.
-
[7]
The most common definition of the informal sector is based on the compliance with labour market legislation (minimum wage, social security contribution, firing procedures). A broader definition reported by Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003, 2004) accounts temporary workers in the formal sector.
-
[8]
They also depend on the indicators used to asses the non compliance with labour market legislation.
-
[9]
The effective rate of protection is defined as the proportional increase in value added resulting from the imposition of protective measures. It measures the percentage by which value added can increase over the free trade level as a consequence of a tariff structure. The effective rate of protection captures protection of intermediate and final goods by tariff or non-tariff protective measures.
-
[10]
The transformation of non-tariffs barriers into tariff equivalent implies an increase in the nominal protection rate of industry and agriculture outputs. This coupled with a significant reduction of the nominal protection on inputs and intermediate goods lead to the rise of the effective rate of protection.
-
[11]
In appendix 1, we also report a second proxy of wage inequality, namely the annual average wage in the tertiary sector relative to that in manufacturing industries. Both ratios exhibit similar trends.
-
[12]
Institut d’économie quantitative.
-
[13]
This sector includes manufacturing industries (IAA, Agro-food industry; IME, Mechanical, electrical and electronic industry; MCCV, Pottery, glass and other non-metallic mineral industry; IC, Chemical industry; THC, Textiles, wearing apparel, leather and footwear industry; IMD), non manufacturing industries (mining, energy, electricity, water, construction) and productive services (telecom, tourism, trade, other services).
-
[14]
1997 was not included due to a large number of aberrant observations in this year.
-
[15]
Sectors considered in computing wage inequality over 1998-2002 are: IAA, IME, IC, THC, IMD, energy, tourism, transport and telecom, trade, renting.
-
[16]
According to Hanson and Harrison (1999a) the neoclassical trade theory implicitly assumes that countries protect relatively more sectors that do not benefit from comparative advantages.
-
[17]
This simple framework is potentially consistent with capital-skill complementarity. Capital is here ignored in order to simplify the model.
-
[18]
Firms are thus not able to capture rents.
-
[19]
We have applied the Mann-Whitney non-parametric test of hypothesis on the ratio WQ/WNQ in order to assess the null hypothesis of equality in variable means over two sub-periods corresponding respectively to (1975-1986) and (1987-2002) (appendix 5, table A5.1). This test rejects the null hypothesis which supports the intuition that trade liberalization exerts a significant impact on wage inequality.
-
[20]
In order to study the impact of trade openness on economic growth, Edwards (1998) regressed total factor productivity on nine trade liberalization indexes.
-
[21]
See Siroën (2001), p. 106.
-
[22]
We regress the specified equation over the following sub-periods: 1975-1998, 1983-1998 and 1998-2002. Unit root tests are performed over the period 1975-1998.
-
[23]
According to (IEQ), an important portion of EU Tunisian imports consists on intermediate goods (37%) and equipments (21%).
-
[24]
The population census carried out by (INS) in 1994 shows that women workers are relatively more educated than men: 51.4% of women workers are college or high-school graduates against 40.5% for men.
-
[25]
See Lefranc (1997), p. 1052.
-
[26]
The trade liberalization effect on wage inequality in Tunisia is nevertheless moderate relatively to that observed in some Latin American countries. The gradual implementation of trade reforms in Tunisia highly contributes to explain this fact.
-
[27]
The author wishes to thank the anonymous referees whose suggestions improved the paper greatly. The author is also grateful to Mr. Mongi Ben Chaâben from the Tunisian Institute of Quantitative economy, Mrs. Rim Ben Ayed Mouelhi, Mr. Jean-Marc Siroën, Mrs. Aude Sztulman and Mr. Mondher Ghazali for helpful comments. This paper benefited from the financial support of the French Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs and the Tunisian Ministry of higher education, scientific research and technology within the framework of the Hubert-Curien partnership program-Utique.
-
[28]
See Maurin and Parent, 1993.